to avoid address abuse, please type it yourself

an excerpt from How to make the dollar sound again

by James Grant, NYTimes, Nov. 13, 2010

in gold we trust

This was on Nov. 3. A general uproar ensued, with the dollar exchange rate weak- ening and the price of gold surging. And when, last Monday, the president of the World Bank suggested, almost diffidently, that there might be a place for gold in today’s international monetary arrangements, you could hear a pin drop.

Let the economists gasp: The classical gold standard, the one that was in place from 1880 to 1914, is what the world needs now. In its utility, economy and ele- gance, there has never been a monetary system like it.

It was simplicity itself. National currencies were backed by gold. If you didn’t like the currency you could exchange it for shiny coins (money was "sound" if it rang when dropped on a counter). Borders were open and money was footloose. It went where it was treated well. In gold-standard countries, government budgets were mainly balanced. Central banks had the single public function of exchanging gold for paper or paper for gold. The public decided which it wanted.

"You can’t go back", today’s central bankers are wont to protest, before adding, "And you shouldn’t, anyway". They seem to forget that we are forever going back (and forth, too), because nothing about money is really new. "Quantitative easing", a k a money-printing, is as old as the hills. Draftsmen of the United States Consti- tution, well recalling the overproduction of the Continental paper dollar, defined money as 'coin'. "To coin money" and "regulate the value thereof" was a Congres- sional power they joined in the same constitutional phrase with that of fixing "the standard of weights and measures." For most of the next 200 years, the dollar was, in fact, defined as a weight of metal. The pure paper era did not begin until 1971.

The Federal Reserve was created in 1913 — by coincidence, the final full year of the original gold standard. (Less functional variants followed in the 1920s and ’40s; no longer could just anybody demand gold for paper, or paper for gold.) At the outset, the Fed was a gold standard central bank. It could not have conjured money even if it had wanted to, as the value of the dollar was fixed under law as one 20.67th of an ounce of gold.

Neither was the Fed concerned with managing the national economy. Fast forward 65 years or so, to the late 1970s, and the Fed would have been unrecognizable to the men who voted it into existence. It was now held responsible for ensuring full employment and stable prices alike.

If only they gave it some thought, though, the economists — nothing if not smart — would fairly jump at the chance for counter duty. For a convertible currency is a sophisticated, self-contained information system. By choosing to hold it, or instead the gold that stands behind it, the people tell the central bank if it has issued too much money or too little. It’s democracy in money, rather than mandarin rule.

Today, it’s the mandarins at the Federal Reserve who decide what interest rate to impose, and what volume of currency to conjure.

 2011-04-17 

2011-04-10
2011-04-03
2011-03-27
2011-03-20
2011-03-13
2011-03-06
2011-02-27
2011-02-20
2011-02-13
2011-02-06
2011-01-30
2011-01-23
2011-01-16
2011-01-09
2011-01-02
2010-12-26
2010-12-19
2010-12-12
2010-12-05
2010-11-28
2010-11-21
2010-11-14
2010-11-07
2010-10-31
2010-10-24
2010-10-17
2010-10-10
2010-10-03

 

previous

 

WEBSITE  EDITOR:
Krešimir J. Adamić